Monday, April 23, 2012

Your future happiness depends less on the present than you might think


You make a lot of decisions based on how you think they will make you feel in the future.  Car dealers ask you to think about how happy you’ll be driving a beautiful new car.  Ads for cruises ask you to think about how great you’ll feel after a relaxing vacation.  On the flip side, people work hard for a new promotion believing that if they don’t advance in their career, they will be devastated.

The evidence is pretty clear, though, that big positive and negative events don’t have an enormous impact on people’s happiness.  In a 1998 paper in the Journal of Personality and Social Psychology Dan Gilbert, Tim Wilson, and their colleagues found that college faculty being evaluated for tenure believed they would be quite unhappy if they were denied tenure.  Several months after their tenure decision, though, college faculty who had been denied tenure were no less happy than those who had gotten tenure. 

This finding that we believe that future positive and negative events have a bigger impact on our future happiness than they do is called an affective forecasting error.  One thing about these errors that is not well understood is why they don’t go away over time.  We all have experience with these errors.  As a kid, I remember toys that I really wanted to get because I had seen them in a catalog.  When I actually got one of those toys, though, it was never quite the life-changing experience I expected.  So, why didn’t examples like this get rid of these affective forecasting errors?

This question was explored in a November 2010 paper in the Journal of Experimental Psychology: General paper by Tom Meyvis, Rebecca Ratner, and Jonathan Levav. 

These researchers find that people have difficulty remembering their initial prediction for how they would feel after a positive or negative event.  In one study, they asked voters in the 2008 election how they would feel a week after the election if Barack Obama won.  Supporters of John McCain rated that they would be quite unhappy.  A week after the election, these same voters were contacted again and asked how happy they were.  They were also asked to recall how happy they said they would be when they predicted it before the election.  These voters were significantly happier than they predicted they would be (that is the affective forecasting error).  They also remembered their prediction as being less extreme than it was.  That is, they did not remember predicting that they would be very unhappy.

The researchers demonstrated that this poor memory for previous predictions makes it hard for people to learn to predict better in the future.  In this study, some people were reminded of their initial prediction, and those people who were reminded of what they actually predicted showed smaller affective forecasting errors in the future.

In the first session of the experiment, people ranked their preference for flavors of jellybeans, and then were asked how much they would enjoy eating jellybeans that they liked moderately well after eating either a jellybean that they really like or one that they don’t like much at all.  People usually predicted that they would like a moderate jellybean less after eating one they really like than after eating one they don’t like at all.  (This is called a contrast effect.)

People came back for a second session, and actually ate sequences of jellybeans and rated their enjoyment.  As it turns out, preference for jellybeans isn’t affected at all by the one you just ate, and so there was an affected forecasting error.  The participants were able to look at their ratings and see that they enjoyed the jellybean equally well regardless of what else they ate.  One group of participants was then shown their original prediction (which showed that they expected a difference in enjoyment).  The other group was not reminded of their original prediction.

Then, everyone did a similar task.  They ranked a series of ice cream flavors.  Then, they were asked how much they would enjoy eating a flavor they like moderately well either after having a spoonful of an ice cream they really enjoy or after having a spoonful they do not like at all.  Obviously, this judgment is quite similar to the one about the jellybeans.

Those people who were reminded of their original judgment with the jellybeans correctly predicted that their enjoyment of ice cream would not be affected much by what they had eaten before.  Those who were not reminded of their earlier judgment predicted that their enjoyment of the ice cream would be influenced by the flavor they ate before.  So, those people who were not given a reminder still showed an affective forecasting error.

Overall, then, it seems like we continue to mis-predict how events will affect our future happiness because we have difficulty remembering the predictions we make.

Do these affective forecasting errors really matter?  In fact, these errors may be both a blessing and a curse.

On the positive side, it can be motivating to be very concerned about a future event.  College faculty approaching tenure are often quite productive in the years before their evaluation, because they believe that the outcome of this decision will have a huge influence on their career.  Even though the actual tenure decision won’t influence their future happiness much, this hard work may still lay important groundwork for their research in years to come.

On the negative side, though, these affective forecasting errors can also lead to bad decisions.  If you really believe that a sports car will make you happier, you may overpay to own it.  That means that you will spend a lot of money on a purchase that ultimately won’t affect your happiness that much. 

On balance, then, it is probably best to remember that there are lots of factors that affect how happy you will be in the future, and that no single event will have that big an influence on that happiness.